Copyright
Like?

The Phillips Curve in the Long Run: Inflation Rate

Start Your Free Trial To Continue Watching
As a member, you'll also get unlimited access to over 8,500 lessons in math, English, science, history, and more. Plus, get practice tests, quizzes, and personalized coaching to help you succeed.
Free 5-day trial
It only takes a minute. You can cancel at any time.
Already registered? Login here for access.
Start your free trial to take this quiz
As a premium member, you can take this quiz and also access over 8,500 fun and engaging lessons in math, English, science, history, and more. Get access today with a FREE trial!
Free 5-day trial
It only takes a minute to get started. You can cancel at any time.
Already registered? Login here for access.
  1. 0:06 The Phillips Curve in the Early 1970s
  2. 3:24 The Phillips Curve in the Long Run
  3. 11:36 Lesson Summary
Show Timeline
Taught by

Jon Nash

Jon has taught Economics and Finance and has an MBA in Finance

How do unemployment and inflation effect each other? In this lesson, you'll discover why the Phillips curve is vertical in the long-run with the help of some real world examples.

The Phillips Curve in the Early 1970s

In the United States, President Richard Nixon had come to office in 1968 with a pledge to bring down inflation, which was between 4% and 5% - higher than it had been since 1951. His economic advisors, using the knowledge that they had at the time, told him that if the government pursued policies that slowed the economy, then inflation would go down, and unemployment, which was already low, would move back up a little bit. Shortly thereafter, the government changed its fiscal policy by reducing government spending in an effort to cool the economy.

Unfortunately, things didn't turn out the way that they predicted. The President and his advisors were shocked when unemployment rose and inflation rose from 4.8% to 5.3%! Not only did these events catch the President and major economists off guard, they stirred up a great debate in the field of macroeconomics that led to some major advances in how economists model the growth of the economy. So what was going on during this time? For the rest of this lesson, we'll find out.

First, let's take a historical look at what led to the economic thinking of that time. In 1958, when A.W.H. Phillips released a study of wages in the United Kingdom, he found that there was an inverse relationship between inflation and unemployment. In other words, when unemployment was high, inflation was low, and when unemployment was low, inflation rose rapidly. Economists call this the Phillips curve. The Phillips curve illustrates the relationship between the rate of inflation and the unemployment rate. The Phillips curve tells us that it may not be possible for an economy to achieve both of the goals of low inflation and low unemployment at the same time.

In the U.S. economy of the 1960s, it appeared that there was a definite tradeoff between the two. It appeared that the government leaders had succeeded in lowering the unemployment rate, but only at the expense of higher inflation. Soon after this discovery, economists began estimating what the Philips curve would be for most other countries, and this theory became widely accepted and taught in major universities across the world. While the Phillips curve held true throughout the entire decade of the 1960s, it fell apart in the early 1970s. Go with me to the town of Ceelo for some more specific examples from everyday life and see the Phillips curve in action.

When Bob's low-rider lawn service feels the effects of an expanding economy, they hire additional employees and raise prices in order to meet the additional demand. When Bob's business feels the pains of a slowing economy, they lay workers off and lower prices in order to adjust to less demand. This is why prices across the economy tend to be higher when unemployment is low and lower when unemployment is high. This is the Phillips curve in action. But while this relationship holds in the short run, it falls apart in the long run.

The Phillips Curve in the Long Run

Let's explore what happens to inflation and unemployment in the long run, first from the standpoint of an expanding economy and then from the standpoint of a recessionary economy.

When the economy is expanding, that means consumers are buying more goods and services - including Bob's lawn service. Bob has hired new employees like other businesses across the economy, so prices are higher and unemployment is lower than usual in the short run. Let's say he has 15 workers and he can mow 150 lawns per week. When businesses like Bob's hire new workers all across the economy, a shortage of workers develops. Not only that, but the workers figure out that prices for goods and services have gone up and they start demanding higher wages. All of a sudden, Bob gets a voicemail from Jerry saying he can't pay his bills and he needs a raise. Then he gets a text message from Doug saying he wants a raise from $10 per hour to $12 per hour or he's long gone. Pretty soon, all his employees get wise and start asking for a raise. Now he has to raise the wages he pays to everyone just to keep them from leaving to work for Jimbo's lawn company down the road (who have slightly better seats on their mowers). These added costs lower Bob's profit and influence him to lay off 5 workers in order to maintain his profit margin. Now, instead of 15 workers, Bob only has 10 workers and can only mow 100 lawns per week.

Graph illustrating movement up the Phillips curve from point A to point B
Phillips Curve Graph

Eventually, however, a shortage of workers develops and workers begin to demand higher wages. When businesses are forced to pay higher wages, what they do instead is lay off workers to protect their profit margins, and that means that the unemployment rate rises back to its natural rate. While economists illustrate an increase in demand as movement along the short-run Phillips curve, they illustrate this long-run scenario we just talked about as a shift of the entire short-run Phillips curve towards the natural rate of unemployment. On the graph, this is shown by moving from point B to point C.

Now let's look at things from the opposite point of view. When the economy is in recession, this means that consumers are buying fewer goods and services - including Bob's lawn service. Responding to lower demand, businesses like Bob's lay off workers all across the economy and prices go down. Instead of 10 workers, Bob now has 7 workers, let's say, which means that in this example he can only mow 75 laws instead of 100.

While unemployment is higher in the short-term, in the long run, things change. Let's look at Bob's business and see how this process unfolds. When unemployment builds up, eventually a surplus of workers develops, and this puts downward pressure on wages. At Bob's low-rider lawn service, Doug, Jerry and James have all applied to work for Bob, and they're all competing for the same position riding a commercial lawnmower. On Tuesday, let's say, Bob receives a gift package delivered to his house with two bottles of his favorite barbecue sauce. On the card, it says 'Your friend forever, Doug.' On Wednesday, Bob opens his mailbox after a hard day at work and finds he is now getting issues of Sports Illustrated courtesy of Jerry. The next day, Bob finds a gift certificate from Outrageous Bodacious Chicken Wings on top of his mower when he starts work. These workers really want this job!

When workers compete with each other for the same jobs, they start accepting lower wages, which means eventually Bob can pay his workers less as this trend filters through the economy. The bright side of lower wages, for Bob at least, is that he can lower the price of his lawn service from, say, $25 to $20 per cut, and this attracts 25 new customers. These new lawn service customers make it necessary for Bob to hire back the employees he previously fired. Now Bob is mowing 100 lawns per week again.

Movement from point B to C reflects the long-run scenario as a downward shift of the short-run curve
Long-Run Phillips Curve

Economists illustrate a decrease in demand as movement down the short-run Phillips curve, shown here as moving from point A to point B. They illustrate this long-run scenario we just talked about as a shift of the entire short-run Phillips curve towards the natural rate of unemployment. On the graph, this is shown by moving from point B to point C.

Unlock Content Over 8,500 lessons in all major subjects

Get FREE access for 5 days,
just create an account.

Start a FREE trial

No obligation, cancel anytime.

Want to learn more?

Select a subject to preview related courses:

People are saying…

"This just saved me about $2,000 and 1 year of my life." — Student

"I learned in 20 minutes what it took 3 months to learn in class." — Student

See more testimonials

Did you like this?
Yes No

Thanks for your feedback!

What didn't you like?

What didn't you like?

Congratulations! You've reached the last video in the chapter.
Start the Next Chapter
Create your Account

Sign up now for your account. Get unlimited access to 8,500 lessons in math, English, science, history, and more.

Meet Our Instructors

Meet all 53 of our instructors